Inflation We Can Feel But Don’t Measure
"Perhaps things are not as great as the official data would have one believe."
By Joshua R. Hendrickson, AIER
In the aftermath of the pandemic, the United States experienced the highest rates of inflation of the last four decades. More recently, inflation rates have been trending lower. Nonetheless, a number of economists have been surprised to observe that consumers aren’t very happy despite signs that the inflation rate is on a trajectory towards the Federal Reserve’s target of two percent. Although a number of economists have been quick to dismiss consumer pessimism or explain that things are actually quite good, a recent paper by economists at Harvard and the IMF offers an explanation for pessimism: perhaps consumer measures of the cost of living differ from the price indices that economists use to measure inflation.
A price index is just a weighted average of prices. People often reference the price index as capturing “the cost of living.” This is indeed the purpose of constructing a price index. Economic theory demonstrates that a measure of the cost of living should track the cost of a basket of goods that provides the consumer with the same level of satisfaction across time. If done properly, this price index not only tracks the average behavior of prices over time, but also tracks the cost of living.
Of course, the construction of a price index is easier said than done. For example, inflation occurs when the supply of money grows faster than the demand for money. Prices could be changing because the money supply is growing too fast. However, supply and demand also fluctuate over time, which results in changes in (relative) prices and quantities. A price index needs to isolate the general trend in money prices from changes in relative prices. In addition, there is a question of what to include in the price index.
A long-standing criticism, first articulated by economists Armen Alchian and Ben Klein, is that the price indices that are used by economists and policymakers exclude interest rates and/or asset prices. Conventional price indices are only consistent with economic theory if we believe that consumers are making once-and-for-all consumption decisions. In reality, consumption today affects consumption in the future. Decisions about what to consume today are influenced by the rates of return on particular assets, the cost of borrowing, and asset prices. As such, these prices should be included in our price indices.
In large part, this is what a new paper by Marijn Bolhuis, Judd Cramer, Karl Schulz, and Larry Summers sets out to do. Although not motivated by Alchian and Klein, they arrive at a similar conclusion. In particular, they point out that consumers tend to think of interest costs as part of the cost of living regardless of what economic theory or a particular price index has to say. They also note that a previous version of the Consumer Price Index (CPI) used to include both housing prices and mortgage costs.
In the paper, the authors construct an alternative version of the CPI that includes “mortgage interest payments, personal interest payments for car loans and other non-housing consumption, and lease prices for vehicles.” What they find is that their alternative measure suggests that the inflation rate peaked at around 18 percent in November 2022 and remained considerably higher at the end of 2023 than the official calculations of CPI would suggest.
These estimates give credence to the negative views that the general public seems to have about the current state of the economy. The authors show that their alternative measure of inflation is capable of explaining why consumer sentiment remains low. Furthermore, they show that this isn’t unique to the United States. They provide evidence from 10 countries that changes in interest rates can explain fluctuations in consumer sentiment that other economic indicators cannot explain. Regardless of whether one thinks that the CPI should include interest rates and/or asset prices, it seems clear that consumers factor in these costs when evaluating the cost of living and describing their views on the state of the economy.
There are a couple of lessons to be drawn from this. First, as Alchian and Klein argued, economic theory implies that a price index that includes interest rates and/or asset prices is superior to one that does not. The new paper from Bolhuis et al. demonstrates that this theoretical concern has important empirical consequences for the measurement of inflation. Second, consumer sentiment is lower than expected given the official rate of inflation and the unemployment rate. The fact that this alternative measure of inflation can explain a significant fraction of the gap between actual consumer sentiment and what one would predict from the official statistics should give economists pause about the official measure of inflation. Rather than assume that they have superior knowledge and information about the state of the economy than the average consumer, perhaps economists should have some humility. Maybe consumers have a better sense of the cost of living than the official statistics. Perhaps things are not as great as the official data would have one believe.
About the Author
Joshua R. Hendrickson is an Associate Professor of Economics at the University of Mississippi. His research interests include monetary theory, history, and policy. He has published articles in leading scholarly journals, including the Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, Journal of Macroeconomics, Economic Inquiry, and the Southern Economic Journal.
Hendrickson earned his Ph.D. in Economics from Wayne State University. He earned his B.A. and M.A. in Economics from the University of Toledo.
QTR’s Disclaimer: I am an idiot and often get things wrong and lose money. I may own or transact in any names mentioned in this piece at any time without warning. Contributor posts and aggregated posts have not been fact checked and are the opinions of their authors. They are either submitted to QTR, reprinted under a Creative Commons license or with the permission of the author. This is not a recommendation to buy or sell any stocks or securities, just my opinions. I often lose money on positions I trade/invest in. I may add any name mentioned in this article and sell any name mentioned in this piece at any time, without further warning. None of this is a solicitation to buy or sell securities. These positions can change immediately as soon as I publish this, with or without notice. You are on your own. Do not make decisions based on my blog. I exist on the fringe. The publisher does not guarantee the accuracy or completeness of the information provided in this page. These are not the opinions of any of my employers, partners, or associates. I did my best to be honest about my disclosures but can’t guarantee I am right; I write these posts after a couple beers sometimes. Also, I just straight up get shit wrong a lot. I mention it twice because it’s that important.
From 180 Degress by Feargus O’Connor Greenwood.
“You need to be open to the idea that everything you’ve been taught is a lie”.
The ‘measurement’ of CPI is primarily facie evidence that the statement above is true.
USG can't be honest about inflation. No investor will purchase Treasury bonds if the yield is lower than the inflation print. If accurate data and free markets determined bond yields, interest rates would jump to 10% or higher. The Feds can't afford it, and neither can the private sector. The result would be a (much needed) market correction, and a (much needed) reduction in deficit spending. It would be painful, but everything would be better in the long run. Instead they manipulate inflation data, and the central bank adds trillions of dollars of demand to the bond market to keep a lid on rates.